Zuerst die Vorwürfe an die wirtschaftsliberalen Kollegen (fett meine Deutung):
und dann die Vorwürfe an die interventionistischen linken Ökonomen:
- Inflation & Hyperinflation: There is excess fear of inflation and hyperinflation in the current economic environment. Further there is often an excess estimate of the costs of inflation in the two to five percent range.
- Determinanten des Wachstum: We know much less about the causes and drivers of economic growth than we like to admit, and when pushed on this issue we fall back to citing relatively simple cases with extreme differences, such as East vs. West Germany.
- Gesamtwirtschaftlicher Ertrag niedriger Steuern: Lower taxes don't spur economic development as much as it is often claimed, at least not below the "fifty percent or less of gdp" range.
- Klimawandel: There are many climate change issues of relevance here, not mostly economics, but it seems remiss not to mention them.
- Privates Gesundheitssystem: I'm all for Health Savings Accounts, but unless done on a Singaporean scale, and with lots of forced savings, they're not a health care plan to significantly benefit most Americans. There is less of a coherent health care plan, coming from this side, than one might like to think.
- Konstenkontrollen im Gesundheitssystem: There is already considerable health care cost control embedded in the ACA, most of all for Medicare, and this is not admitted with sufficient frequency.
- Unterschätzen der Wichtigkeit der Staaten in der Wirtschaftsgeschichte: When it comes to the historical determinants of the Industrial Revolution, the Great Divergence, and the like, the importance of state-building in that process is often neglected.
- The story of steady and significant economic progress for most Americans is accepted too readily.
- Unterschätzen der Marktfehler in der Finanzkrise: The role of market failure in the recent financial crisis is underestimated. It is also believed that we can somehow commit to a policy of no future bailouts. Promoting that myth will make future bailouts more likely.
- Relying on liability law, whether or not it is a good idea, is not intrinsically more pro-market, more libertarian, or less interventionist.
- Überbetonen der Bedeutung von Geld in der Politik: Suggesting that money matters in politics far more than the peer-reviewed evidence indicates.
- Einzelevaluierungen von Staatsausgaben: Evaluating government spending on a program-by-program basis, rather than viewing the budget as a series of integrated accounts. Cross check with the phrase "Social Security," or for use to take many discretionary spending cuts off the table.
- Nichtberücksichtigung politökonomischer Aspekte: A reluctance to incorporate sophisticated "public choice" theories into the analysis of favored programs.
- Sins of omission: there are plenty of bad policies, such as occupational licensing, which fail to come under much attack from the left. Sometimes this is because the critique would run counter to the narrative of needing more government or needing more regulation.
- Überschätzen der Gewerkschaften: Significantly overestimating the quality of the political economy of an America with more powerful labor unions and underestimating the history of labor unions as racist, corrupt, protectionist, and obstructions to positive change.
- Überschätzung des Effekts von Fiskalpolitik und Unterschätzung der Geldpolitik: Overestimating the efficacy of fiscal policy, underestimating the power of monetary policy, and sometimes ignoring or neglecting how the two interact ("the monetary authority moves last").
- Citing weak versions of structural unemployment theories and dismissing them with a single sentence or graph, while relying on stronger versions of structural theories in other, non-cyclical contexts.
- Lack of interest in discussing ethnicity and IQ as relevant for social policy, except in preferred contexts.
- Überoptimistische Einschätzungen der Fiskalpositionen von Gebietskörperschaften: Overly optimistic views of the fiscal positions of state governments. Since the states don't have the same tax-raising powers that the feds do, and since state government spending is favored, there is a tendency to see these fiscal crises as not so severe, or as caused by mere obstructionists who will not raise taxes to the required levels.
- A willingness to think that one has "done one's best" in the realm of policy, and to blame subsequent policy failures on Republican implementation, rather than admitting that a policy which cannot be implemented by both political parties is perhaps not a good policy in the first place.
- Use of a strong moral argument for universal health care coverage, combined with a fairly practical, hard-headed approach to the scope of the mandate, and not realizing the tension between the two. Failure to indicate where the "bleeding heart" argument actually should stop and at what margins we should (and will) let non-elderly people die, if only stochastically.
- Implicitly constructing a two-stage moral theory, which first cordons off the sphere of the nation-state (public goods provision, etc.) and then pushing cosmopolitan questions off the agenda in the interests of expanding a social welfare state. (In fairness, many individuals on the right don't give cosmopolitan considerations even this much consideration, although right-oriented economists tend to be quite cosmopolitan.)
- Selektion bestimmter Vorbildstaaten: What about countries? Classical liberals are increasingly facing up to the enduring successes of the Nordic nations. There is not always a similar reckoning with the successes of Chile and Hong Kong and Singapore; often this is a sin of omission.
- Reluctance to admit how hard the climate change problem will be to solve, for fear of wrecking any emerging political consensus on taking action.
Für jeden etwas da?
Keine Kommentare:
Kommentar veröffentlichen